Prices, and Production: Lecture III, Part VI

Published Tue, Sep 8 2009 1:49 AM | laminustacitus

At last, an answer to the question posed in the first lecture, that of how it comes about that the economy cannot utilizes all existing resource (which Hayek attests is “the central task of any theory of industrial fluctuations”1), and without having to base the analysis on the assumption that unused resources exist. Rather than elucidating the process of economic recovery, Hayek felt that is was more worthwhile to discuss important conclusions of the preceding theory.

Based on the business cycle contained in the preceding lecture, it is all by certain that granting credits to consumers, which has been lauded as a method of curing depressions by increasing consumer demand, would only worsen a depression. A relative increase in the demand for consumer goods would only make affairs worse by further skewing a structure of production that is in the process of reallocating resources in a sustainable arrangement after a prior boom-bust cycle. All that those consumer credits would do is a further delaying of a long-term structure of production based on the demands of the market.

However, producers' credits are not so simple. In theory, it is at least plausible that the granting of producers' credits could have a beneficial effect when, in the acute stages of the recession, the structure of production shrinks more than what would be necessary. This would only be the case if the quantity were regulated so to compensate for the initial rise in the prices of consumer goods compared to producers', and if arrangements were made to withdrawal the additional money as the prices fall as the proportion between the supply of the two adapts itself with the demand for the two. Nevertheless, the credits would do more harm than good if their quantity were not strictly regulated, and Hayek's later essay: “The Use of Knowledge in Society”shows, sine dubio, elucidates the impossibility of doing so.

In the end, we return to a time-old conclusion that the only way of avoiding a recession is to check credit expansion in time; but, if that proves to be impossible, then the recession must run its natural course. From the above investigation, conclusions with regard to the methods used in an analysis of business fluctuations follow:

 

The first is that our explanation of the different behavior of the prices of specific and nonspecific goods should help to substitute for the rough empirical classifications of prices according to their sensitiveness, a classification built upon more rational considerations. The second, that the average movements of general prices show us nothing of the really relevant facts; indeed, the index numbers generally used will, as a general rule, fail even to attain their immediate object because, being for practical reasons almost exclusively based on prices of goods of a nonspecific character, the data used are never random samples in the sense required by statistical method, but always a biased selection which can give only a picture of the peculiar movements of prices of goods of this class. And third is that for similar reasons every attempt to find a statistical measure in the form of a general average of the total volume of production, or the total volume of trade, or general business activity, or whatever one may call it, will only result in veiling the really significant phenomena, the changes in the structure of production to which I have been drawing your attention in the last two lectures.2

 

 

1Hayek, 274

2Hayek, 276