Free Capitalist Network - Community Archive
Mises Community Archive
An online community for fans of Austrian economics and libertarianism, featuring forums, user blogs, and more.

"Big Business will Dominate the free market"?

rated by 0 users
Answered (Verified) This post has 1 verified answer | 19 Replies | 5 Followers

Not Ranked
Male
18 Posts
Points 525
Matthew posted on Wed, Apr 20 2011 10:32 AM

Okay, I'm having a discussion with a socialist/statist about the free market, monopoly, and anti-trust laws (repeal them!). I'm getting to the point where my austro-libertarian knowledge is incomplete. He says:

It is a major financial commitment for a startup to stock and staff a store. As soon as they do, bang! Down the prices go down the street!
Is it "peaceful" to attack competitors with your superior economic strength?
If you think it is, then you must agree with my contention that free markets will always end up with a very few dominant players is correct, because that is the inevitable result.
Do you think that the best interests of society are served when a dominant business can dictate prices and drive out competitors?

How do I respond to this?

Answered (Verified) Verified Answer

Top 10 Contributor
6,953 Posts
Points 118,135
Verified by Matthew

Matthew:
How do I respond to this?

He's talking about "predatory pricing."  It's true he has no understanding of business, entrepreneurship or economics.  Send him a copy of the rest of this post:

 

People will say things like "once they've got a foothold in a community, what's to stop them from raising their prices, too? Absolutely nothing."

That's why this old and popular myth of economics is known as "predatory pricing." Sounds scary right? You know this one. It's basically the idea that a big firm that can afford to sell products at a loss for a while (i.e. for less than they paid for them) will drop their prices so low that smaller firms will be driven out of business. After the competition has been forced out of the market, the predatory firm raises its price, compensating itself for the money it lost while it was engaged in predatory pricing, and earns monopoly profits forever after.

Sounds logical right? The problem with this is, it doesn't work economically...and (therefore as you would expect) there are virtually no examples of this occurring. There has never been a single clear-cut example of a monopoly created by so-called predatory pricing, let alone one in which prices were raised drastically and customers were "gouged." Claims of predatory pricing are typically made by competitors who are either unwilling or unable to cut their own prices. And as I stated, this is not just a situation in which we have no examples...it economically doesn't work...and has been shown for decades to not work.

Here's a short video that tells a really great story of when a big firm tried predatory pricing against a very smart fellow whose name you've probably heard of.

 


For anyone interested in the actual economics of the theory, I've provided several resources below, some of which actually contain references to dozens more. But for the Cliff's Notes kids, I'll just offer some highlights just for those interested (my comments are in italics in the brackets):
 

Quote:
Predatory pricing is the Rodney Dangerfield of economic theory--it gets virtually no respect from economists. But it is still a popular legal and political theory for several reasons. First, huge sums of money are involved in predatory pricing litigation, which guarantees that the antitrust bar will always be fond of the theory of predatory pricing. [...]

Second, because it seems plausible at first, the idea of predatory pricing lends itself to political demagoguery, especially when combined with xenophobia. The specter of a foreign conspiracy to take over American industries one by one is extremely popular in folk myth. Protectionist members of Congress frequently invoke that myth in attempts to protect businesses in their districts from foreign competition.

Third, ideological anti-business pressure groups, such as Citizen Action, a self-styled consumer group, also employ the predatory pricing tale in their efforts to discredit capitalism and promote greater governmental control of industry. Citizen Action perennially attacks the oil industry for either raising or cutting prices. When oil and gas prices go up, Citizen Action holds a press conference to denounce alleged price gouging. When prices go down, it can be relied on to issue a "study" claiming that the price reductions are part of a grand conspiracy to rid the market of all competitors. And when prices remain constant, pricefixing conspiracies are frequently alleged.

Fourth, predatory pricing is a convenient weapon for businesses that do not want to match their competitors' price cutting. Filing an antitrust lawsuit is a common alternative to competing by cutting prices or improving product quality, or both.

Finally, some economists still embrace the theory of predatory pricing. But their support for the notion is based entirely on highly stylized "models," not on actual experience.1

["In other words, predatory pricing theory persists because well-placed
individuals and organizations that benefit from accusing others of engaging
in predatory pricing will use their resources to keep the theory alive."2]

Quote:
The theory of predatory pricing can be likened to that strange gift from Aunt Maude or a unicorn. [...]

There is another problem with predatory pricing, however, that is just as pressing as the “unicorn” problem. Economists generally attempt to explain firm behavior by using standard neoclassical instruments. As this article demonstrates, however, the neoclassical theory of the firm, as expressed by the use of the standard neo-Marshallian tools depicting imperfect competition, does not grant users the intellectual apparatus by which to conclude that firms, given the assumptions of profit-maximizing behavior, would engage in an activity like predatory pricing. [...] [E]ven some of the theory’s supporters uneasily accede to its unicorn-like characteristics, as I point out later.2

[in other words, not only can no one point to a single example of predatory pricing occurring, but the economic models that even supporters of the predatory pricing theory use to try to show it could happen, don't work the way they should...They contradict...and this has led even the supporters to have to admit their theory basically has no economic basis.]

[...]Shughart writes that if one examines the actions and risks firms must undertake in order to engage in illegal predation, it “does not pay” (1990, p. 296). McGee (1958) writes that predatory pricing cannot be thought of as a rational business strategy because the “predatory” firm in the end is likely to suffer greater losses than its rivals.

Other economists, including Stigler (1967) and Telser (1966) have attacked such a strategy because it conflicts with the assumption of rational behavior by firm owners. Isaac and Smith (1985) examined a number of predatory pricing cases and concluded that they were unable to ascertain whether or not the firms accused actually had engaged in such practices.2

Quote:
First, it should not at all be taken for granted that the large, rich firm is even in a position to impose a price reduction below the small firm's costs. At the lower price it asks, there will be an increase in the quantity of the good demanded. The large firm can make the lower price effective only if it is in a position to supply this additional quantity demanded. Whether or not it can do so depends on how elastic the demand for the product is in response to the price reduction[...]and also on how much unused productive capacity the firm has on hand and that is available for the particular market concerned. If its capacity is insufficient to meet the larger quantity demanded, it has no means of compelling its small competitor to sell at the lower price it asks. For in this case, customers who come to it in order to obtain the lower price must be turned away. They will have to deal with the smaller firm.[...]

A further, much greater difficulty arises. If it is the case that as soon as the small competitor is driven out, the large firm can sharply increase its price, while so long as the small competitor remains in business the price is held below the level of his costs, then usually unrecognized but nonetheless extremely powerful interests are created on behalf of the continued existence of the small competitor.

[...]A less obvious interest in the continued existence of the small competitor is that of the industry's suppliers and that of the producers of products that are complementary to the industry's products.3


[in other words, as long as the smaller competitor is around, everyone gets to enjoy the extremely low prices of the predatory firm...so there is a lot of interest in keeping that competitor around...namely, not just by the competitor himself, but by the suppliers and complementary producers of the industry. They would all be very interested in keeping the smaller firm around...not only to enjoy the lower prices of the predatory firm, but to avoid any higher prices the firm might try to charge in the future.]

And he actually goes on and on. Another big one is the concept of brand reputation. If every time a new competitor pops up, you drop your prices to compete, and then the competitor disappears, and you jack up your prices, how long will it take before people just won't shop at your store? There is a lot to be said for reputation and brand loyalty. If the choice is between a new place that is giving good service and reasonable prices that stay reasonable, people will choose that over a quixotic price changer pretty darn quick.

If you're interested in more reasons why it never works, I highly recommend following the links to sources #1 and #3. Reisman goes into great detail, but provides very simple, easy to understand examples.



1 - DiLorenzo, Thomas J. 1992. “The Myth of Predatory Pricing,” Policy Analysis No. 169. Cato Institute; http://mx.nthu.edu.tw/~cshwang/teach...03-06-monopoly and profit/DiLorenzo=THE MYTH OF PREDATORY PRICING.pdf

2 - Anderson, William L. 2003. "Pounding Square Pegs into Round Holes: Another Look at the Neo-Classical Theory of Predatory Pricing." The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, Vol. 6, Spring; http://mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae6_1_2.pdf

3 - Reisman, George. 1998. Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics. Ottawa, IL: Jameson Books. pp. 399-407; http://www.capitalism.net/Capitalism...M_Internet.pdf

4 - http://mises.org/daily/226

5 - Isaac, R. Mark, and Vernon L. Smith. 1985. “In Search of Predatory Pricing.” Journal of Political Economy 93: 320–45.

All Replies

Top 75 Contributor
1,010 Posts
Points 17,405

He forgets one of the most elementary aspects of capitalism: credit! There's no such thing as superior economic strength. If there's money to be earned, a new competitor can borrow money.

"They all look upon progressing material improvement as upon a self-acting process." - Ludwig von Mises
  • | Post Points: 5
Not Ranked
8 Posts
Points 100
AngelRS replied on Wed, Apr 20 2011 10:52 AM

This is the kind of thinking of one who:

A) Has never run a business

and

B) Thinks low price is the only way to compete

Unless you find a new way to create a good with less expense than a major corporation, you can't win on the front of low price.

The solution is to find a "niche" or specific way to sell to your market. Better marketing, different products, positioning, etc.

Frankly, the market doesn't care who is a big business or a small one. You either learn to channel and use the demand of consumers, or you flop. Pretty simple.

A big business may dominate a section of the market. Fortunately, there are many sections. Trying to dominate them all would be far and beyond the budget of any company.

I actually suggest reading Positioning: The Battle For Your Mind by Al Ries and Jack Trout. Shows you how a business can enter the market strategically and even use the size of their competitor against them.

 

  • | Post Points: 5
Top 500 Contributor
349 Posts
Points 5,915
Mtn Dew replied on Wed, Apr 20 2011 11:04 AM

I would imagine if an entrepreneur sees that a market is there he'll start a business. If the evil big business lowers prices then consumers win. If the process repeats consumers win again. Even his straw man argument doesn't sound so bad to me.

  • | Post Points: 5
Top 25 Contributor
Male
4,249 Posts
Points 70,775

Ask him to first summarize what Rothbard says here [in section (4)  “Cutthroat” Competition] about why it is a non issue, then to explain why Rohbard is wrong.

My humble blog

It's easy to refute an argument if you first misrepresent it. William Keizer

  • | Post Points: 5
Top 500 Contributor
Male
358 Posts
Points 8,245

Ask him why this doesn't happen now. The regulators (FTC/DOJ) don't see a case for every new store that opens in a market, so "predatory pricing" if possible, is still profitable. Especially regarding smallish businesses, they never get accused/taken to court over monopolistic pricing--it just isn't profitable for the courts to do so.

  • | Post Points: 20
Not Ranked
22 Posts
Points 415
Othyem replied on Wed, Apr 20 2011 12:25 PM

Tell him to go read Kevin Carson.

  • | Post Points: 5
Top 10 Contributor
Male
6,885 Posts
Points 121,845

Big businesses do dominate the market... with the help of the State. And it is no surprise that prices go down when a new competitor enters the market, elementary economic theory predicts that this should happen. Businessmen cannot blindly plan as if their entrance into the market will not affect the market. If burgers are selling for $5 you cannot build your business plan so that it will fail if you cannot sell your burgers for at least $5. You need to be able to survive even if burger prices fall to $4.50 or $4 and this is the role of capitalization and part and parcel of why capitalism is so important. The businessman with a good idea and a good reputation can seek to partner with venture capitalists with an appetite for risk in search of returns. If he's sufficiently capitalized, he will be able to withstand market downturns or even organized attacks.

The most important point is to remember that "attacking" competitors with low prices, in a free market, is a recipe for bankruptcy. Selling below the optimal price results in losses not greater profits. The established player already has the advantage against the newcomer by virtue of the fact that he is operating in the black where the newcomer is almost invariably operating in the red. The established player is giving up that advantage if he slashes prices to "attack" the newcomer. A properly capitalized newcomer will be able to leverage such suicidal behavior to gain market share that much faster.

But when big business is holding hands with the State it has a partner with unlimited funds. Competition against an opponent with unlimited funds determined to drive any newcomers to bankruptcy through price wars is impossible. Wal-Mart's market cap is just $187 billion. That's just 10 days of US Federal government spending. I would much rather compete against Wal-Mart without the Feds than against a much smaller company with the Feds on their side.

Clayton -

http://voluntaryistreader.wordpress.com
  • | Post Points: 5
Top 10 Contributor
6,953 Posts
Points 118,135
Verified by Matthew

Matthew:
How do I respond to this?

He's talking about "predatory pricing."  It's true he has no understanding of business, entrepreneurship or economics.  Send him a copy of the rest of this post:

 

People will say things like "once they've got a foothold in a community, what's to stop them from raising their prices, too? Absolutely nothing."

That's why this old and popular myth of economics is known as "predatory pricing." Sounds scary right? You know this one. It's basically the idea that a big firm that can afford to sell products at a loss for a while (i.e. for less than they paid for them) will drop their prices so low that smaller firms will be driven out of business. After the competition has been forced out of the market, the predatory firm raises its price, compensating itself for the money it lost while it was engaged in predatory pricing, and earns monopoly profits forever after.

Sounds logical right? The problem with this is, it doesn't work economically...and (therefore as you would expect) there are virtually no examples of this occurring. There has never been a single clear-cut example of a monopoly created by so-called predatory pricing, let alone one in which prices were raised drastically and customers were "gouged." Claims of predatory pricing are typically made by competitors who are either unwilling or unable to cut their own prices. And as I stated, this is not just a situation in which we have no examples...it economically doesn't work...and has been shown for decades to not work.

Here's a short video that tells a really great story of when a big firm tried predatory pricing against a very smart fellow whose name you've probably heard of.

 


For anyone interested in the actual economics of the theory, I've provided several resources below, some of which actually contain references to dozens more. But for the Cliff's Notes kids, I'll just offer some highlights just for those interested (my comments are in italics in the brackets):
 

Quote:
Predatory pricing is the Rodney Dangerfield of economic theory--it gets virtually no respect from economists. But it is still a popular legal and political theory for several reasons. First, huge sums of money are involved in predatory pricing litigation, which guarantees that the antitrust bar will always be fond of the theory of predatory pricing. [...]

Second, because it seems plausible at first, the idea of predatory pricing lends itself to political demagoguery, especially when combined with xenophobia. The specter of a foreign conspiracy to take over American industries one by one is extremely popular in folk myth. Protectionist members of Congress frequently invoke that myth in attempts to protect businesses in their districts from foreign competition.

Third, ideological anti-business pressure groups, such as Citizen Action, a self-styled consumer group, also employ the predatory pricing tale in their efforts to discredit capitalism and promote greater governmental control of industry. Citizen Action perennially attacks the oil industry for either raising or cutting prices. When oil and gas prices go up, Citizen Action holds a press conference to denounce alleged price gouging. When prices go down, it can be relied on to issue a "study" claiming that the price reductions are part of a grand conspiracy to rid the market of all competitors. And when prices remain constant, pricefixing conspiracies are frequently alleged.

Fourth, predatory pricing is a convenient weapon for businesses that do not want to match their competitors' price cutting. Filing an antitrust lawsuit is a common alternative to competing by cutting prices or improving product quality, or both.

Finally, some economists still embrace the theory of predatory pricing. But their support for the notion is based entirely on highly stylized "models," not on actual experience.1

["In other words, predatory pricing theory persists because well-placed
individuals and organizations that benefit from accusing others of engaging
in predatory pricing will use their resources to keep the theory alive."2]

Quote:
The theory of predatory pricing can be likened to that strange gift from Aunt Maude or a unicorn. [...]

There is another problem with predatory pricing, however, that is just as pressing as the “unicorn” problem. Economists generally attempt to explain firm behavior by using standard neoclassical instruments. As this article demonstrates, however, the neoclassical theory of the firm, as expressed by the use of the standard neo-Marshallian tools depicting imperfect competition, does not grant users the intellectual apparatus by which to conclude that firms, given the assumptions of profit-maximizing behavior, would engage in an activity like predatory pricing. [...] [E]ven some of the theory’s supporters uneasily accede to its unicorn-like characteristics, as I point out later.2

[in other words, not only can no one point to a single example of predatory pricing occurring, but the economic models that even supporters of the predatory pricing theory use to try to show it could happen, don't work the way they should...They contradict...and this has led even the supporters to have to admit their theory basically has no economic basis.]

[...]Shughart writes that if one examines the actions and risks firms must undertake in order to engage in illegal predation, it “does not pay” (1990, p. 296). McGee (1958) writes that predatory pricing cannot be thought of as a rational business strategy because the “predatory” firm in the end is likely to suffer greater losses than its rivals.

Other economists, including Stigler (1967) and Telser (1966) have attacked such a strategy because it conflicts with the assumption of rational behavior by firm owners. Isaac and Smith (1985) examined a number of predatory pricing cases and concluded that they were unable to ascertain whether or not the firms accused actually had engaged in such practices.2

Quote:
First, it should not at all be taken for granted that the large, rich firm is even in a position to impose a price reduction below the small firm's costs. At the lower price it asks, there will be an increase in the quantity of the good demanded. The large firm can make the lower price effective only if it is in a position to supply this additional quantity demanded. Whether or not it can do so depends on how elastic the demand for the product is in response to the price reduction[...]and also on how much unused productive capacity the firm has on hand and that is available for the particular market concerned. If its capacity is insufficient to meet the larger quantity demanded, it has no means of compelling its small competitor to sell at the lower price it asks. For in this case, customers who come to it in order to obtain the lower price must be turned away. They will have to deal with the smaller firm.[...]

A further, much greater difficulty arises. If it is the case that as soon as the small competitor is driven out, the large firm can sharply increase its price, while so long as the small competitor remains in business the price is held below the level of his costs, then usually unrecognized but nonetheless extremely powerful interests are created on behalf of the continued existence of the small competitor.

[...]A less obvious interest in the continued existence of the small competitor is that of the industry's suppliers and that of the producers of products that are complementary to the industry's products.3


[in other words, as long as the smaller competitor is around, everyone gets to enjoy the extremely low prices of the predatory firm...so there is a lot of interest in keeping that competitor around...namely, not just by the competitor himself, but by the suppliers and complementary producers of the industry. They would all be very interested in keeping the smaller firm around...not only to enjoy the lower prices of the predatory firm, but to avoid any higher prices the firm might try to charge in the future.]

And he actually goes on and on. Another big one is the concept of brand reputation. If every time a new competitor pops up, you drop your prices to compete, and then the competitor disappears, and you jack up your prices, how long will it take before people just won't shop at your store? There is a lot to be said for reputation and brand loyalty. If the choice is between a new place that is giving good service and reasonable prices that stay reasonable, people will choose that over a quixotic price changer pretty darn quick.

If you're interested in more reasons why it never works, I highly recommend following the links to sources #1 and #3. Reisman goes into great detail, but provides very simple, easy to understand examples.



1 - DiLorenzo, Thomas J. 1992. “The Myth of Predatory Pricing,” Policy Analysis No. 169. Cato Institute; http://mx.nthu.edu.tw/~cshwang/teach...03-06-monopoly and profit/DiLorenzo=THE MYTH OF PREDATORY PRICING.pdf

2 - Anderson, William L. 2003. "Pounding Square Pegs into Round Holes: Another Look at the Neo-Classical Theory of Predatory Pricing." The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, Vol. 6, Spring; http://mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae6_1_2.pdf

3 - Reisman, George. 1998. Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics. Ottawa, IL: Jameson Books. pp. 399-407; http://www.capitalism.net/Capitalism...M_Internet.pdf

4 - http://mises.org/daily/226

5 - Isaac, R. Mark, and Vernon L. Smith. 1985. “In Search of Predatory Pricing.” Journal of Political Economy 93: 320–45.

Top 75 Contributor
1,010 Posts
Points 17,405

Is the expectation of a price war a barrier in the market that keeps competitors out? For example, a company is the only provider of electricity to a small rural town, and can therefore demand monopoly prices. What keeps competitors out is the cost of building another landline. But competitors want to get some of those high profits too, so the first company can never raise prices above where it would be worthwhile to build another landline. But...! if they actually do that there would be a price war and neither company would make a lot of profits. Which means that building another landline is unlikely to be worth the cost. But the first company knows that, so it is free to raise prices as much as it wants.

"They all look upon progressing material improvement as upon a self-acting process." - Ludwig von Mises
  • | Post Points: 20
Top 10 Contributor
6,953 Posts
Points 118,135

So you pay higher prices for the increased burden it takes to get electricity or phone or cable services out to your middle-of-nowhere area.  So what?

Why in the world should someone who chooses to live somewhere that it is more difficult to get services to him not have to shoulder the cost of getting those services?  If you don't want to pay more, go live somewhere closer to what you want to buy.  You don't want to pay $5/gallon for gasoline?  Then don't live in Hawaii.

By the same token, if you want the benefit of lower prices from competition, don't live in a small town where there's one grocery store, one repair shop, and one appliance store.  Hell.  You're lucky those services are even there at all.  Plenty of people have to drive for an hour or more just to get to a store of any kind.

  • | Post Points: 20
Not Ranked
Male
18 Posts
Points 525

Lots of great replies here. Thanks to all for the information.

I don't think I'll ever convert this socialist, but maybe the next one...

BTW I am not familiar with the verify answer system. I picked the one with the most information, but the others were good too.

  • | Post Points: 5
Top 150 Contributor
Male
630 Posts
Points 9,425

What about the example of an organisation producing chairs within a town and then a big importer business opens up in town and starts selling chairs. They are importing the chairs from china and selling them by the 1000s. The local chair seller struggles to compete and goes out of business.

Another example is where you have two shops right next to each other selling the same thing and due to one being a franchise they can sell beer and other products cheaper. The non franchised one goes out of business.

So not necessarily "big business" but just improved production, distribution and logistics, this can cause a reduction in cost without any loss in quality. For the consumer cheaper prices and better products is a good thing, but it does happen in today’s society and people do lose their businesses.

  • | Post Points: 20
Top 50 Contributor
Male
2,209 Posts
Points 35,645
Merlin replied on Thu, Apr 21 2011 4:56 PM

 

Why would he assume government beurocrats would do better than a private ubercompany? Had that been the case, we'd all be writing in French here, and New York would be Nouvelle Marseille.

The Regression theorem is a memetic equivalent of the Theory of Evolution. To say that the former precludes the free emergence of fiat currencies makes no more sense that to hold that the latter precludes the natural emergence of multicellular organisms.
  • | Post Points: 5
Top 75 Contributor
1,010 Posts
Points 17,405

John James:
So you pay higher prices for the increased burden it takes to get electricity or phone or cable services out to your middle-of-nowhere area...

Yes, I know. You don't have to give me the rhetoric. I was asking whether this dilemma has a free market solution, like the predatory pricing one. Making it about rural electricity lines is just a way to easier illustrate the point. We can use any business instead. Say a cornflakes manufacturer has some natural advantage over it's competitors, so there is a slight barrier to entry and he has a large market share. In on itself that's nothing bad, people still get the best deal. If he tries to exploit his position beyond his natural advantage, others will compete with him because they want a piece of the pie. So the story goes. But, and here comes my question, competitors know that once they compete with him there will be a price war and not a lot of profit to be had, won't that act as a barrier to entry?

"They all look upon progressing material improvement as upon a self-acting process." - Ludwig von Mises
  • | Post Points: 5
Page 1 of 2 (20 items) 1 2 Next > | RSS